Households should rent or pledge the land of adjacent farming households to
take advantage of economies of scale. Households can also buy additional land
(accounting for 25.27% of the total farmers' opinions) of neighboring households or
buy land in other areas of the region under the support of the Government from the
Loan policy with preferential interest rates.
Collaborate with neighboring small-scale rice households to expand
production scale with groups, rice cultivation groups or cooperatives.
Households can participate in a large model field to take advantage of the farm
size and government's support policies.
Households and businesses need to link up to establish "large sample fields"
and establish specialized farming areas associated with Viet GAP standards.
28 trang |
Chia sẻ: honganh20 | Ngày: 01/03/2022 | Lượt xem: 352 | Lượt tải: 0
Bạn đang xem trước 20 trang tài liệu Tóm tắt Luận án Determining the optimal farm size in agricultural production of households Mekong delta, để xem tài liệu hoàn chỉnh bạn click vào nút DOWNLOAD ở trên
techniques with the relevant technology level (Li et al., 2013)
and this is also the index not affected by the price of inputs as well as the price of
output products. Therefore, the thesis uses TFP criteria to determine the optimal farm
size threshold to maximize HQHDSX, at the same time, the thesis still analyzes the
other four criteria as a basis to prove the assertion that “each of these indicators is
not the best measure the efficiency of production activities”.
2.1.2 Theoretical basis of the influence of farm size on the efficiency of
production activities
Wickramaarachchi and Weerahewa (2018) productivity is defined as the ability
of an input unit to produce a given output unit. Agricultural productivity shows the
level of efficiency of households in using a specific input with a certain level of
technology.
The inverse relationship between farm size and the efficiency of production
activities plays an important role in many regions at different times and this
relationship was first discovered in agricultural production in Russia by Chayanov
(1926), then inherited and developed widely in the 1960s and 1970s (Sen, 1962;
Bardhan, 1973). Sen (1962) the small farms in India, which obtaining higher the
efficiency of production activities as they apply more inputs (especially family
labor). Berry and Cline (1979) also demonstrated a relationship similar to Sen in
other developing countries and Deolalikar (1981) argued that this relationship was
only true in traditional agriculture. This relationship became a hotly debated topic
between agricultural economists and development economists (Carter, 1984; Feder,
1985; Benjamin, 1995).
Imperfections in the market of inputs also contribute to the formation of a
strong inverse relationship between farm size and the efficiency of production
activities. First, the analysis of data from fifteen developing countries, Cornia (1985)
shows that systematic output per unit of agricultural land decreases as the farm size
of increase by labor is more abundant and cheaper for small farm. Head of
households' knowledge of land and local climatic conditions accumulated over
generations contributes to an advantage over hiring workers (Rosenzweign and
Wolpin, 1985). The advantage of supervision and knowledge of small farm will
compensate for difficulties in accessing capital and formal insurance in rural markets
(Feder, 1985). An inverse relationship between fram size and the efficiency of
production activities is caused by the imperfections of credit and labor markets when
8
combined with fixed costs of production (Eswaran and Kotwal, 1986). Imperfection
land and insurance motivate smallholders to use more family labor to reduce the
potential adverse effects of price fluctuations (Barrett, 1996). Assuncao and Ghatak
(2003) demonstrated an inverse relationship after controlling households'
heterogeneity of skills. Thapa (2007) also discovered this relationship in Nepal
because it used more labor and cash than large farms. Ansoms et al. (2008) found a
strong inverse relationship between farm size and the efficiency of production
activities Rwanda due to the scarcity of land that forced households to over-exploit
their resources in the case of main household income from agricultural production.
The research also found that increases in non-farm wages and technological
advances will affect the exchange rate, management capacity, presence and level of
market imperfections. It is these factors that will form the inverse relationship
between farm size and HQHDSX (Otsuka, 2013).
However, a number of other studies also explain the existence of inverse
relationships due to the omission of other factors that affect the HQHDSX such as
knowledge and technical understanding as well as socio-economic environmental
issues. In which households must make decisions (Kalirajan, 1990) and based on
previous researches, two of the socio-economic environmental indicators (include
education and income other than agriculture) have been selected to measure the
relationship between farm size and HQHDSX (Bravo – Ureta and Pinheiro, 1997),
differences between households (Assuncao and Ghatak, 2003), land fragmentation
(Wu et al., 2005), differences in soil quality (Benjamin, 1992; Lamb, 2003;
Assuncao and Braido, 2007), soil characteristics and sand content (Barrett et al.,
2010) and the other factors, at the same time omitting the different definitions that
show the HQHDSX. Therefore, Li et al. (2013), Wickramaarach and Weerahewa
(2018) added exogenous variables to control the influence of these factors on the
efficiency of rice production activities of households. However, the level of the
impact of the inverse relationship between farm size and HQHDSX tends to decline
over time (Deininger and Byerlee, 2012; Deininger et al., 2015) due to the
emergence of imperfect labor markets and technological change.
On the contrary, some researches have demonstrated a positive relationship
between farm size and the efficiency of production activities, meaning that large
farm are more effective than small farm. The emergence of a Green Revolution has
increased the role of capital and knowledge, which has led to the emergence of large
farm achieving a higher level of HQHDSX in districts suitable for new technologies
(Deolalikar, 1981). Recent innovations in plant breeding, tillage and information
technology help households easier monitor labor, thus increasing the efficiency of
production activites in traditional agriculture at Eastern Europe and South America
(Helfand and Levine, 2004; Lissitsa and Odening, 2005). And this positive
9
relationship was also discovered in Nigeria due to the high quality inputs used by
large farm of the households (Obasi, 2007), in Japan that having relatively well
factor markets (Kawasaki, 2010) and China due to technological development and
technological transformation (Chen et al., 2011).
Mixed results obtained by Rahman and Rahman (2009) suggest that a positive
relationship between HQHDSX and farm size occurs in advanced technology areas
and the inverse relationship still exists in developing regions. Tamel (2011) in the
US agriculture sector showed that in some areas, farm size and the efficiency of
production activities is positive but in others may have a positive relationship
(Kawasaki, 2010; Ali and Deininger, 2015; Lu et al., 2018) or the negative
relationship (Paul and Githinji, 2017) with farm size depending on the fragmentation
process. Hence, the inverse relationship is a local phenomenon rather than an
indispensable law in production.
The researches not only stop at a simple relationship (negative or positive
relationsgip) but also show a nonlinear relationship (U-shaped or ∩-shaped) between
farm size and HQHDSX. First, Mahmood and Nadeem-ul-haque (1981) have
demonstrated the U-shaped nonlinear relationship between farm size and HQHDSX
when estimating the inputs (farm size, square farm size) with output. Inheriting that
achievement, researchers Byiringiro and Reardon (1996), Heltberg (1998b) have
added the characteristics of soil and region characteristics, followed by Helfand and
Levine (2004) and Ali and Deininger (2015) developed Heltberg's model on the basis
of adding soil characteristics.
However, Dorward (1999), Kimhi (2006), Barrett et al. (2010), Ali and
Deininger (2015), Nkonde et al. (2015), Henderson (2015), Anseeuw et al. (2016),
Wickramaarachchi and Weerahewa (2018) argue that there is an inverted U-shaped
nonlinear relationship between farm size and HQHDSX through different models
from simple (only farm size variables and squared farm size) to the complete model
of information and characteristics of the head of household, land characteristics and
quality, the ability to manage and care for rice fields, ... all show this relationship.
2.1.3 Theoretical backgrounds of optimal farm size
According to economic theory and economics of agricultural production
theory, Debertin (2002) demonstrated the optimal input threshold to maximize the
output through the first derivative calculation method based on specific inputs.
According to Greene (2003), consider finding the x where f(x) is maximized
or minimized. Because f’(x) is the slope of f(x), either optimum must occur where
𝑓ᇱ(𝑥) = 0. Otherwise, the function will be increasing or decreasing at x. This result
implies the first-order or necessary condition for an optimum maximum or minimum
is ௗ௬
ௗ௫
= 0. Hence, to maximize or minimize a function of several variables, the first-
10
order conditions are డ(௫)
డ௫
= 0
According to microeconomic theory, when the smaller farm, the higher the
average cost will increase, and the larger farm expands, the lower the average cost
will decrease, until a certain farm size (or the maximum farm size) the average cost
will be the minimum and if the optimal farm size is exceeded, the average cost will
increase with increasing farm size, which results in the opposite of the production
function, implies obtain the largest average yield for the optimal farm size.
According to Wickramaarachchi and Weerahewa (2018), the optimal farm size
is the farm size at which the HQHDSX is maximized. Because when farm size is
still small, if farm size continues to expand, the effectiveness will increase and
achieve the highest efficiency at the optimal farm size threshold. At this farm size
threshold, if farm size continues to expand, the efficiency decreases and the optimal
farm size threshold is determined by ఉభ
ଶఉమ
.
2.2 Overview of references
2.2.1 The research of the effects of farm size on the efficiency of production
activities
2.2.1.1 Effect of farm size on land productivity
The inverse relationship is discussed and discovered through theory and
experiment on many countries around the world (Mazumdar, 1965; Bharadwaj,
1974; Khan, 1977; Chaddha, 1978; Berry and Cline, 1979; Carter, 1984 ; Cornia,
1985; Feder, 1985; Bhalla and Roy, 1988; Chattopadhyay and Sengupta, 1997;
Heltberg, 1998a&b; Assuncao and Ghatak, 2003; Fan and Chan-Kang, 2005; Barrett
et al., 2010; Chen et al., 2011; Sial et al., 2012; Carletto et al., 2013; Holden and
Fisher, 2013; Ali and Deininger, 2015; Desiere and Jolliffe, 2017) but with a focus
on India (Sen, 1962; Bardhan, 1973; Ghose, 1979; Newell et al., 1997; Assuncao
and Braido, 2007; Gaurav and Mishra, 2015).
However, there are also many studies disagreeing with the above hypothesis
and based on empirical evidence that have provided the opposite opinion, that large
farm households will be more effective than households with small farm (Rao, 1966;
Srivastave et al., 1973; Heltberg, 1998a&b; Khan, 1979; Khan and Maki, 1979; Rao
and Chotigeat, 1981; Kevane, 1996; Akram-Lodhi, 2001; Van Hung and et al., 2007;
Truong Hong Vo Tuan Kiet and Hua Tuan Tai, 2013; Akudugu, 2016).
Thus, farm size can have an impact on land productivity in two dimensions,
showing economies of scale and non-economies of scale. Studies (Mahmood and
Nadeem-ul-haque, 1981; Byiringiro and Reardon, 1996; Heltberg, 1998b; Ali and
Deininger, 2015) have demonstrated a U-shaped nonlinear relationship between
farm size and land productivity. However, Dorward (1999), Barrett et al. (2010), Ali
11
and Deininger (2015), Nkonde et al. (2015), Henderson (2015), Anseeuw et al
(2016), Wickramaarachchi and Weerahewa, 2018 suggest that having an inverted U-
shaped nonlinear relationship between farm size and land productivity.
2.2.1.2 The effect of farm size on labor productivity
The efficiency of production activities is measured by labor productivity that
is not as commonly researched as land productivity but has been researched in recent
years and shows a positive relationship between farm size and labor productivity
(Lamb, 2003; Li et al., 2013; Adamopoulos and Restuccia, 2014).
Researchers Byiringiro and Reardon (1996), Nkonde et al. (2015),
Wickramaarachchi and Weerahewa (2018) also found an inverted U-shaped
nonlinear relationship between farm size and labor productivity based on energy
estimation labor productivity with different explanatory variables such as farm size,
square farm size, variables showing the characteristics of the household head, the
characteristics of the land, and differences in the residence area.
2.2.1.3 Effect of farm size on capital efficiency
Although there are very few studies on this relationship, it still shows a clear
relationship like other HQHDSX. First, Li et al. (2013), Wickramaarachchi and
Weerahewa (2018) used capital efficiency measure to measure HQHDSX and show
the positive relationship between farm size and capital efficiency. However, Nkonde
et al. (2015) measured the capital efficiency use through cost efficiency and found
an inverted U-shaped nonlinear relationship between farm size and capital efficiency
in all three cases from single, semi-complete to complete variables.
2.2.1.4 The effect of farm size on economic efficiency
Many researches have demonstrated an inverse relationship between farm size
and economic efficiency (Lau and Yotopoulos, 1971; Tadesse and Krishnamoorthy,
1997; Bagi, 1982; Townsend et al., 1998; Xu and Jeffrey, 1998; Gorton and
Davidova, 2004; Manjunatha et al., 2013). In contrast, Hall and Leveen (1978), Lund
and Hill (1979), Hoque (1988), Kalaitzandonakes et al. (1992), Sharma et al. (1999),
Alvarez and Arias (2004), Rios and Shively (2005), Tipi et al. (2009), Nguyen Huu
Dang (2012) have demonstrated the positive relationship between farm size and
production efficiency.
Researchers not only stop in the linear relationship between farm size and
production efficiency but also research and make judgments about the existence of
nonlinear relationship between farm size and production efficiency. The U-shaped
relationship between farm size and production efficiency is shown through the
varius research of (Helfand and Levine, 2004). In contrast, Hoque (1988), Nguyen
Tien Dung and Le Khuong Ninh (2015), Nguyen Tien Dung (2015) have
demonstrated the inverted U-shaped nonlinear relationship between farm size and
12
production efficiency.
2.2.1.5 The effect of farm size on the total factor productivity
Although the relationship between farm size and TFP is not as deeply
concerned as the relationship between farm size and land productivity. However,
it still shows that there may be a linear relationship (negative or positive
relationship) between TFP and farm size or nonlinear relationship through some
empirical researches. First, Van Zyl et al. (1996), Li et al. (2013), Gautam and
Ahmed (2018) found an inverse relationship between farm size and TFP. In
contrast, other researches have found a positive relationship between farm size and
TFP through experiments in Czech Republic (Hughes, 1998), in Slovakia (Hughes,
2000), in Vietnam (Dinh Bao, 2014) and in Australia (Sheng and Chacellor, 2018).
The research also found nonlinear relationship between farm size and TFP in
two different forms. The U-shaped nonlinear relationship between farm size and
TFP through the research of Nkonde et al. (2015) have proved that the inverted U-
shaped nonlinear relationship between farm size and TFP.
2.2.1.6 The effect of farm size on the efficiency of production activities
As just stated, most researcges only use a single measure of HQHDSX, in
which land productivity is commonly used in many researches to explore the
relationship between farm size and HQHDSX. Other ways of measuring HQHDSX
such as labor productivity, capital efficiency, technical efficiency and TFP are
rarely used. In recent years, a comprehensive measurement of the HQHDSX
through various measurement aspects (using 3-5 measurements) was conducted by
Li et al. (2013), Nkonde et al. (2015), Wickramaarachchi and Weerahewa (2018)
have demonstrated a different relationship (linear as negative or positive
relationship, U-shaped or inverted U-shaped nonlinear relationship) between farm
size and HQHDSX depending on the measurement specifically the efficiency of
production activities.
2.2.2 Researches on optimal farm size
Many researches have demonstrated the optimal farm size threshold to
maximize the efficiency of production activities according to one of five different
measurements in the same data set (researches from 3-5 measures representing the
HQHDSX) or different data set (single research a measure of HQHDSX). On the
basis of the first derivative or ఉభ
ଶఉమ
based on the estimation results of the model of
factors affecting on HQHDSX (Hoque, 1988; Hassanpour, 2013; Nguyen Tien
Dung, 2015; Nkonde et al., 2015; Wickramaarachchi and Weerahewa, 2018)
2.3 Research methods
2.3.1 Research framework
Labor
Productivity
Optimal farm
size by NSLD
Land
Productivity
Optimal farm size
by NSDAT
13
Source:Research and design
Hình 2.1 Proposes research framework
2.3.2 Data collection
The study selected three provinces in the Mekong Delta with the same
characteristics of the land with large farm rice cultivation of An Giang, Dong Thap
and an average of Can Tho. The study collected randomly 498 rice-producing
households in the Autumn-Winter 2016, Winter-Spring 2017 and Summer 2017
seasons, of which An Giang (225 households), Can Tho (90 households) and Dong
Thap (183 households).
2.3.3 Data analysis
Objective 1: Research using descriptive statistical methods
Objective 2: Research to use 2 ways:
- A two-step estimation method for four ways of measuring the efficiency of
production activities including land productivity, labor productivity, capital
efficiency and TFP.
- An one-step estimation method for economic efficiency measure.
Objective 3: Use necessary conditions and calculation formula of Greene
(2003), Wickramaarachchi và Weerahewa (2018):
𝜕𝐻𝑄𝐻𝐷𝑆𝑋(𝑄𝑀𝐷𝐴𝑇)
𝜕𝑄𝑀𝐷𝐴𝑇
= 0 => 𝑄𝑀𝐷𝐴𝑇 =
𝛽ଵ
2𝛽ଶ
(2.7)
Objective 4: rely on the achieved results to propose the most effective solutions
2.4 Estimation model of farm size impacts on the efficiency of rice production
activities of Mekong Delta households
The general model measures the impact of farm size on the efficiency of
production activities through various aspects as follows:
14
𝐻𝑄𝐻𝐷𝑆𝑋 = 𝛽 + 𝛽ଵ𝑄𝑀𝐷𝐴𝑇 + 𝛽ଶ𝑄𝑀𝐷𝐴𝑇𝑆𝑄 + 𝛽ଷ𝑄𝑀𝐿𝐷 + 𝛽ସ𝑁𝑈𝐶𝐻 + 𝛽ହ𝑇𝐷𝐻𝑉𝐶𝐻
+ 𝛽𝑇𝑁𝐾𝐻𝐴𝐶 + 𝛽𝑆𝑂𝑀𝐴𝑁𝐻 + 𝛽଼𝐿𝐷𝑇𝐻𝑈𝐸 + 𝛽ଽ𝐿𝐷𝐺𝐷
+ 𝛽ଵ𝐴𝑁𝐺𝐼𝐴𝑁𝐺 + 𝛽ଵଵ𝐷𝑂𝑁𝐺𝑇𝐻𝐴𝑃 + 𝛽ଵଶ𝑇𝑉𝑂𝑁 + 𝛽ଵଷ𝑇𝐻𝐴𝑀𝑁𝐼𝐸𝑁
+ 𝛽ଵସ𝐾𝐶𝑅𝑈𝑂𝑁𝐺 + 𝛽ଵହ𝑇𝐴𝑃𝐻𝑈𝐴𝑁 + 𝜀 (2.8)
where: HQHDSXk is the efficiency of production activities measured by
different aspects, QMDAT is the farm size of rice cultivation on the largest field (ha),
QMDATSQ is the square of farm size of the household, QMLD is the number of
working-age members of the family involved in rice production (number of
employees), NUCH is the dummy variable representing the gender of the head of
household (= 1 if the head of household is female and = 0 otherwise) , TDHVCH is
the educational level of the head of household (number of classes), TNKHAC is the
household's non-rice income (million VND /year), SOMANH is the number of rice
plots of the household (the number of plots), LDTHUE is the total labor days hired
to work in rice fields (days/ha), LDGD is the total number of family labor days
working on rice fields (days/crop), ANGIANG (= 1 if the household lives in An
Giang and = 0 if in other province), and DONGTHAP (= 1 if the household lives in
Dong Thap and = 0 if in another province), TVON is the total cost of the inputs
(including family labor) (million VND/crop), THAMNIEN is the number of years
of rice farming experience of the head of the household (year), KCRUONG is the
distance from the household to the largest field (km), TAPHUAN (= 1 if the head of
the household participated in training courses in the last 3 years and = 0 if otherwise),
i indicate the number of i rice the households and j showing the number of j crops.
15
CHAPTER 3. OVERVIEW OF RESEARCH AREAS
This chapter presents an overview of the Mekong Delta as well as of the
provinces surveyed mainly regarding farm size.
3.1 Land resources in the Mekong Delta
Land area in the survey area is concentrated on alluvial soil. This soil group
has high fertility and balance, favorable for agricultural production, especially for
rice, coconut, sugarcane, pineapple and fruit trees.
3.2 Current status of rice production
3.2.1 Farm size in the Mekong Delta
* Farm size of agricultural production
Number of agricultural households in the Mekong Delta in general and the
three researched provinces in particular concentrated mainly on the farm size of 0.5
- 2 ha, accounting for 40.36%, followed by the scale of 0.2 - 0.5 ha accounts for
25.13% and the remaining is allocated at other ones.
Table 3.1 Number of households using agricultural land in the Mekong Delta by farm size
Unit: Household
Location 2 ha Total
An Giang 37.887 36.339 68.427 27.395 170.048
Can Tho 20.942 26.850 43.264 11.151 102.207
Dong Thap 49.341 53.713 89.269 24.086 216.409
Mekong Delta 509.795 598.932 961.914 312.455 2.383.335
Nguồn:Tổng điều tra nông thôn, nông nghiệp và thủy sản Việt Nam năm 2016
* Farm size of rice cultivation by locality
Source:General Statistics Office 2017
Figure 3.1 Scale of paddy land in the Mekong Delta by location
Farm size of rice cultivation is concentrated in An Giang, followed by Dong
Thap and at least Can Tho. This result forms the number of households surveyed in
the provinces in the study area.
* Farm size of rice cultivation by scale
The total number of rice-growing households in the Mekong Delta accounts
for 19.12% of the total number of rice-growing households nationwide and
concentrates on the scale of 0.5 - 2 ha. The number of rice-growing households in
Dong Thap is higher than the other two provinces and when divided by farming size,
0
2000
4000
6000
2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017
ĐBSCL
Đồng Tháp
An Giang
Cần Thơ
16
the farming scale of the people of 3 provinces of An Giang, Can Tho and Dong Thap
is still similar to households in the Mekong Delta, which means that most people
cultivate on a scale of 0.5 - 2 ha, accounting for about 40%, from 0.2 to 0.5 ha,
accounting for 25% and under 0.5 ha accounts for about 22% and the scale of over
2 ha accounts for about 13%. This implies that people in the surveyed area are
cultivating on a small farm and fragmented so not really bring about optimal the
efficiency of production activities.
Source: Vietnam Rural, Agriculture and Fishery Census 2016
Figure 3.2 Structure of households using rice land in the Mekong Delta by scale
3.2.2 Results of rice production in the research area
Source: General Statistics Office 2017
Figure 3.3 Rice production in the Mekong Delta 2010 - 2017
Rice production in the three provinces of An Giang, Dong Thap and Can Tho
followed the increasing trend over time for the whole period but began to decline
slightly in 2016, of which the highest output of An Giang and Can Tho was the
lowest. Can Tho has the lowest output but the growth rate is quite high when
compared to 2010 and 2017 at about 16%, reaching the highest output of 1,408
million tons in 2015. For An Giang and Dong Thap due to the large output, the
downward trend in the following years is more evident although the output increased
during the period of more than 6% and 14% for each province. To conclude, the
output of the provinces has increased but started to decline slightly in the following
years and slower than the area so the provinces have lower productivity in the
following years.
0.00
20.00
40.00
60.00
2 ha
An Giang
Cần Thơ
Đồng Tháp
ĐBSCL
0.00
2,000.00
4,000.00
6,000.00
2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 Sơ bộ
2017
Đồng Tháp An Giang Cần Thơ
17
CHAPTER 4. RESEARCH RESULTS AND DISCUSSION
This chapter presents and discusses the results of each study. From there,
proposing solutions for effective use of farm size contributes to improving the
efficiency of production activities, improving incomes and raising the living
standards of households in the Mekong Delta.
4.1 Actual situation of rice production in Mekong Delta households
4.1.1 Land
Table 4.1 Actual situation of farmland
Soil tyle Households (m
2/household) Average (m2/person)
Average (%) Bình quân Tỷ lệ (%)
Residential 755,63 3,93 172,52 3,93
Agricultural 18.401,43 95,82 4.201,24 95,82
Aquaculture
Các file đính kèm theo tài liệu này:
- tom_tat_luan_an_determining_the_optimal_farm_size_in_agricul.pdf