Đề tài Determinants of poverty reduction potential of land in rural vietnam

TABLE OF CONTENTS

 

ACKNOWLEDGEMENT i

ABSTACT ii

LIST OF TABLES iii

LIST OF ABBRIVIATIONS v

CHAPTER I 1

INTRODUCTION 1

1.1 Research topic 1

1.2 Research objectives, scope and focus of the study 2

1.3 Research questions 2

1.4 Methodology 2

1.5 Data 3

1.6 Structure of the thesis 3

CHAPTER II

METHODOLOGICAL FRAMEWORK 4

I. Theoretical framework 4

II. Econometric specification of the welfare equation 6

III. Literature review 7

CHAPTER III

OVERVIEW OF LAND ALLOCATION IN VIETNAM’ AGRARIAN TRANSITION AND POVERTY 10

I. OVERVIEW OF LAND ALLOCATION IN VIETNAM’ AGRARIAN TRANSITION 10

1.1 Land reform in Vietnam 10

1.2 The process of land allocation 14

1.3 Land use in Vietnam 15

II. POVERTY IN VIETNAM 17

2.1. Overall Poverty in Vietnam 17

2.2 Dimensions of poverty in Vietnam 17

2.3 Summary of characteristics of poverty in Vietnam 20

CHAPTER IV

ESTIMATION RESULTS OF HOUSEHOLD WELFARE 22

I. DATA 22

II. DESCRIPTION OF VARIABLES 23

1. Dependent variable 23

2. Explanatory variables 23

III.ESTIMATION RESULTS: The household welfare generating potential of land 25

SUMMARY OF FINDINGS 29

CHAPTER V

CONCLUSION AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS 30

I. CONCLUSION 30

II. POLICY IMPLICATIONS 30

III. SUGGESTION FOR FURTHER STUDY 31

REFERENCES 32

APPENDICES 35

 

 

doc45 trang | Chia sẻ: maiphuongdc | Lượt xem: 1695 | Lượt tải: 0download
Bạn đang xem trước 20 trang tài liệu Đề tài Determinants of poverty reduction potential of land in rural vietnam, để xem tài liệu hoàn chỉnh bạn click vào nút DOWNLOAD ở trên
particularly the conversion of paddy areas (that have traditionally grown, and are often still required to grow, rice) to other crops. As Vietnam participates into the world market and reduces trade barriers in line with ASEAN Free Trade Area (AFTA) and WTO requirements, farmers are becoming increasingly vulnerable to falling incomes because of lower prices for their produce on world markets, and a lack of flexibility to change enterprises will condemn many to increased poverty. A brief overview of recent land reforms in Vietnam Kerkvliet (2000, p. 1) writes “it is hard to think of a more politically controversial resource in Vietnam during the 20th century than farm land”. Conflicts over land policy (access to, and the ownership and use of land) have been integral to the period of French colonial rule, the conflict with America and the policies of the Communist Party government after re-unification of Vietnam in 1975. After a period of collectivization of agricultural land lasting from the late 1950s to the late 1970s, there was an official policy shift in 1981 when the party's Central Committee introduced a “product contract” system. This “Contract 100”, as it was known, authorized cooperatives to assign parcels of land to individual households on an annual basis and contract directly with these households to undertake the planting, care and harvesting of rice and other crops. The harvested product, however, still mostly belonged to the cooperative. This “product contract” system was the pre-cursor to future more far reaching reforms that would consolidate the agricultural household as the primary unit of agricultural production by allocating land use rights to households, and lead to a period of sustained agricultural growth. Further pressure for economic reforms in the 1980s resulted in the doi moi resolutions of 1986. Kerkvliet (1995, p.411) writes that the objective was to "radically deal with a number of mistakes in agriculture accumulated over the years," which included the "forced advance to big-scale cooperatives, lack of encouragement to family economy, (and) inadequate attention paid to (the) private economy”. The 1988 “Resolution 10” gave households greater “production rights” (including the right to sell their farm products) and began the process of land allocation on a more permanent basis. The 1993 Land Law granted farmers increased security of tenure over the land that they had been allocated. Land use rights were granted for 20 years for land used for annual crops, and 50 years for land used for perennial crops. Land use rights also included “five rights” – the rights of transfer, exchange, lease, inheritance and mortgage. The Land Law also put a ceiling on the amount of land that can be allocated to households: for annually cropped land this is 2 hectares in the central and northern provinces and 3 hectares in the southern provinces, and for land planted to perennials the limit on holdings is 10 hectares. Revisions to the Land Law in 1998 (Circular No. 346/1998/TT-TCDC, 1998) sought to encourage and facilitate the process of land allocation and registration by outlining procedures and designating responsibilities, and added two new land rights, including the right to use land (including rented land) as capital for joint ventures. The revisions also set out the circumstances for allowing land related changes, and procedures for registration of changes. As might reasonably be expected, land use rights are not free of legislative requirements and constraints. As noted by the East Asia Analytical Unit (1997, p. 27) the ability to transfer, lease, exchange, mortgage or inherit land use rights “varies between different categories of land, landholders and land use rights. Transactions are subject to official approval case by case”. Land related changes that are officially required to be registered with the local authorities include: changing the land use purposes stated in the certificate, re-shaping land plots, changing the land tenure right, using land as a mortgage at banks for borrowings, altering the land use duration, and sub-leasing land. Registration can only be made after the changes are “permitted by the People’s Committee of the competent level and effected in accordance with current regulations” (Circular No. 346/1998/TT-TCDC, 1998, p. 87). Registration of land-related changes incurs a fee. Further revisions in 1999 addressed complaints about the lack of procedures for “implementation” of land use rights (for example: The World Bank in Vietnam, 1998, p. 36). Decree No 17/1999/ND-CP (1999) set out the conditions and procedures for exchange, transfer, lease, inheritance and mortgage of land use rights. The conditions and procedure for land use rights exchange appear straightforward. Exchange of land may occur if “it is convenient for production and livelihood” and “the land must be used for the right purposes and within the term set by the State when the land is assigned” (Decree No 17/1999/ND-CP,1999, p. 15). Conditions for the transfer and lease of land appear stricter, especially for wet rice land (paddy). Households (or individuals) can only transfer land use rights if they move to other places of residence to live or take up production or business activities, change to other occupations or have no capacity to work. The land use right can only be transferred to households or individuals who have the demand to use the land and have no land or a land area less than the land limit. If the transferred land is wet rice land, then the land use right can only be transferred to a household or individual “directly involved in agricultural production” (Decree No 17/1999/ND-CP, 1999, p. 16). Transfer of a land use right involves payment of a tax on the transfer by the transferor, and payment of a registration fee by the transferee. Likewise, conditions apply for the leasing of land use rights. Households can make their land use rights available for lease if the family is in poverty, if they have taken up other occupations or if they lack capacity to work the land. Generally, land is only able to be leased for 3 years, except for “particularly difficult cases as certified by the commune/ ward/township People’s Committee”, and then the lease can be up to 10 years (Decree No 17/1999/ND-CP, 1999, p. 17). Subleasing of land is allowed, but only if the lease money has been paid in advance and the duration of the lease has at least 5 years still to run. Rental and land transfer values do not reflect true market prices, but rather are determined within a pricing framework set by the Central Government, with the actual prices fixed by the provincial or municipal authorities. Land limits are not rigidly enforced in all areas – especially when there is unused land, but limits hold in the heavily populated delta areas. Although, theoretically, households cannot be transferred land use rights in excess of the land limit, provision is made for households to be able to work land in excess of the limit. Land transferred in excess of the limit must be leased from the State. Lease money is not always charged however, especially for land not considered highly productive (for example, “barren hills” in upland areas). The process of land reform in Vietnam is on going, and another revision to the Land Law has recently been passed by the National Assembly and took effect in October 2001. Considerable pressure is being exerted on the government in relation to the completion of allocation and registration of land use rights, issues related to compensation and the desirability of stable and long-term tenure (for example: Vietnam News, 2000b; Mai, 2001). There is also ongoing debate about the appropriate length of tenure, ceiling levels for land holdings and restrictions on the transfer and use of land. The process of land allocation Approximately 80 percent of the populations of some 80 million people live in rural areas and there are over 11 million household farms in Vietnam (GSO 2002). Farm sizes vary throughout the country, but they are typically small. The average size of farms in the Mekong Delta is 1.2 hectares, and this is considerably larger than average farm sizes in the Red River Delta is 0.28 hectares (GSO 2003). The allocation of land use rights is officially undertaken by the General Department for Land Administration, with certificates of title for agricultural land issued by the District People’s Councils. In practice however, the State allocates land use rights through People's Committees at the district and commune level (East Asia Analytical Unit, 1997; The World Bank in Vietnam, 1998). The October 2001 revisions to the Land Law have given local authorities more power to deal with matters such as allocation and leasing of land, and the issuing of land use right certificates. Since 1993, the process of land allocation in rural areas has been proceeding steadily, along with the necessary mapping that precedes allocation and certification, although a number of problems have arisen with the allocation of forest land (The World Bank in Vietnam, 1998, pp. 35-36): “Directive 10-1998/CT-TTg (20/2/98) claims that 60% of households with rights to 65% of agricultural land have been issued certificates of title. … Only 9.8% of forest land (of which only 1% is natural forest) has been allocated. Local authorities are having to grapple with the complex issues involved in marrying the terms of the 1993 Land Law with customary land-use patterns and rights. The scope for disputes is large since customary owners may vigorously contest the allocation of individual rights.” The allocation process varies between districts, although equity between households was a primary consideration in the land allocation, with consideration being given both to land quality and the number of people, or more specifically labors equivalents, in a household. Consequently, the amount of land allocated varied between households and this land was typically split into a number of plots of varying land quality. The World Bank in Vietnam (1998, p. 10) says “on average, farms in the Red River Delta comprise eight or nine noncontiguous plots often no largerthan 200 to 500 square meters each”. Likewise, Chung (1994, p. 4) reports that in the Red River Delta “households held three to ten plots of farm land scattered in different locations”. In mountainous areas, the number of plots allocated to households tended to be even greater, as the land quality was extremely variable. In the South of Vietnam, the degree of land fragmentation is not so pronounced, with many farmers in the Mekong Delta having only one plot. Be (2000b) suggests that in the South, farmers were “less concerned” with equitable distribution and negotiations took place at District Committee level to “balance” the size of allocations giving consideration to the varying quality of land, and farmers were then allocated larger consolidated parcels. Land allocation to households in the south of Vietnam was also more likely to be based on earlier allocations made during the land reforms of 1975. Typically, not all land within a commune was allocated. A proportion of land was kept (usually between 5 and 10 percent) “to defray public expenses or readjust land allocation periodically to demographic changes such as family members returning from military service” (Chung, 1994, p.4). Other land such as ponds, lakes and garden areas which are difficult to divide, were often also left unallocated, and then assigned to individual households on the basis of competitive bidding. Land use in Vietnam Under the Vietnamese Constitution, land is the property of the people as a whole and the State administers it on their behalf. Since land is 'owned' by the people as a whole, it is not possible for individuals (or corporations) to own land, although they (and foreigners) can own and transfer structures such as houses built on land. However, Vietnamese (but not foreign) individuals, households and organizations can hold and transfer rights to use land. Recent changes to the Land Law made in October 2001 will make it possible for some categories of overseas Vietnamese (Viet Kieu) to hold land use rights. Vietnam has a large population and limited land and, like other countries with high population to land ratio, the value of land is high, and use rights are very important. These rights are crucial to improved private sector development but there are ideological issues that remain important (Fforde, 1995; East Asia Analytical Unit, 1997; AusAID, 2001). Fforde (1995) talks of the difference between Western and Vietnamese understanding of the concepts of public and private land. ‘Private’ land has always been “land over which the local community had considerable residual rights” (p. 93). Hence Fforde (1995, p. 93) argues that “In practice, it is very hard to imagine that various implications of a western concept of private property in land would be accepted – for example, that rice land offered as collateral on a loan by a family should be taken upon foreclosure without the village’s permission.” Other ideological issues relate to the use of land. Land use should be complete (day du), that is, all land should be used; and reasonable, that is, the land should be farmed efficiently with appropriate crops and rotations and attention paid to maintaining the fertility of the land (Tien, 2000b). In practice, this is determined by restrictions on land use that are specified on the certificate of land use rights. There are conflicting views about to what extent the use of land should be the province of the individual or controlled by the State. However, the centrality of state land management to government policies is still paramount (AusAID, 2001). For example, the Hanoi People’s Committee confiscated over 50 hectares of “illegally used” land in late 2001 and early 2002 (Vietnam News, 2002a). These concerns on the use of land are linked closely to issues of rice policy and food security. Shortages of food were commonplace in the mid- 1980s and that is not so long ago. In some districts control over production in still exerted by the State, particularly with regard to rice production (The World Bank in Vietnam, 1998). Production targets are set at a local level in response to government directives and individual households may have to grow crops as directed. Some 4 million hectares of land in Vietnam is still ‘required’ to grow rice, although this represents a decrease of 0.2 million hectares on land previously set aside for rice production (Vietnam News, 2000c). Table 1 - Major annual crops grown in Vietnam, 1995-2000 Year Area of each crop as a percentage of total area under all annual crops Food crops Annual industrial crops Rice Maize Sweet potato Cassava Sugarcane Peanut Soy-bean 1995 73.3 6.0 3.3 3.0 2.4 2.8 1.3 1996 73.8 6.5 3.2 2.9 2.5 2.8 1.2 1997 73.3 6.8 2.8 2.6 2.7 2.6 1.1 1998 73.5 6.5 2.5 2.4 2.8 2.7 1.3 1999 73.1 6.6 2.6 2.2 3.3 2.4 1.2 2000a 73.3 6.8 2.5 2.2 2.9 2.3 1.2 Note: a - Figures for 2000 are preliminary Source: Adapted from data reported by GSO (2001). Percentage land areas planted to some major annual food and industrial crops are given in Table 1. The percentage area planted to rice appears quite stable and kept at quite high ratio for long time, while there has been some increase in the percentage area planted to sugarcane and maize and some decrease in the percentage area planted to sweet potato and cassava (both comparatively low value food crops). POVERTY IN VIETNAM Overall Poverty in Vietnam Table 2 shows that Doi Moi also resulted in an impressive reduction of poverty in Vietnam. It is estimated that before 1986 the national poverty in Vietnam ranged between 74 and 78% (Dollar and Litvack 1998). No matter what poverty measure is selected, all figures indicate that poverty incidence has more than halved in only one decade after the implementation of economic reforms. Indicators in the Table 2 also show that the percentage of the population living below the poverty line declined from over 70 per cent at the end of 1980s to 58 percent in 1993, reducing to 37 per cent in 1998, and kept at 29 per cent in 2002. The proportion of the food-poor decreased from 25 per cent in 1993 to 15 per cent in 1998 and 11 per cent in 2002. Table 2: Indicators of poverty in Vietnam 1990-2002 INDICATORS ON POVERTY AND INEQUALITY (IN %) 1990 1993 1998 2002 National poverty rate (GSO) 70 58.1 37.4 28.9 Food poverty rate (GSO) Na 24.9 15.0 10.9 Poverty gap (GSO) Na 18.5 9.5 6.9 Poverty gap squared (GSO) Na 8.3 3.6 2.6 Sources: Worldbank (2003), Steering Committee of CPRGS (2003) and MPI Poverty line of GSO/World Bank Concept = 2100 kl/person/day = 1,916 thousands VND/person/year (price in 2002) Dimensions of poverty in Vietnam As already presented above, Vietnam’s economic growth over the past decades was associated with a remarkably strong overall reduction of poverty incidences. However, the household survey data also point to significant changes in the rates of poverty reduction once they are disaggregated into the most relevant dimensions. I deliver a more detail information of the spatial dimensions of poverty (see Table 3). Table 3: Spatial dimensions of poverty and inequality in Vietnam POVERTY RATES (HEADCOUNT INDEX %) SHARE OF POPULATION (IN %) YEARS 1993 1998 2002 1993 1998 2002 National dimensions 58. 1 37.4 28.9 100 100 100 Regional dimension Northern Uplands 81.5 64.2 43.9 15.6 18 15 + North East 86.1 62 38.4 - - - - 12 + North West 81.0 73.4 68.0 - - - - 3 Red River Delta 62.7 29.3 22.4 21.6 20 22 North Central Coast 74.5 48.1 43.9 12.8 14 13 South Central Coast 47.2 34.5 25.2 12.6 11 8 Central Highlands 70.0 52.4 51.8 3.2 4 6 South East 37.0 12.2 10.6 12.6 13 15 Mekong Delta 47.1 36.9 23.4 22.4 21 21 Area dimension Urban areas 25.1 9.2 6.6 19.9 20.9 23.23 Rural areas 66.4 45.5 35.6 80.1 79.1 76.77 Source: World bank (2003) and GSO. Regions are defined as in 2002. As in the table 3 reveals, some regions like South East and Mekong Delta and South Central Coast had lower incidences of poverty than the national average throughout all periods. Red River Delta joined this group in the second phase of growth. North Central Coast, North West and North East and Central Highlands in the south are characterized by incidences of poverty higher than the national average in all periods. Regional poverty incidences are closely related to area poverty rates, since the regions with disproportional reduction in poverty are those with a higher share of urban areas, whereas Central Highlands and North West are mainly rural regions. The figures show that poverty is still considerable higher among rural households where are the overwhelming majority in Vietnam. Table 4: Ethnic and gender dimensions of poverty in Vietnam POVERTY RATES (HEADCOUNT INDEX IN %) SHARE OF POPULATION (IN %) YEARS 1993 1998 2002 1993 1998 2002 Ethnic dimension Kinh and Chinese 53.9 31.1 23.1 86.9 85.3 84.2 Ethnic minorities 86.4 75.2 69.3 13.1 14.7 15.8 Gender dimension Male-headed households 61 40 31 77.5 78.4 77.58 Female-headed households 48 28 20 22.5 21.6 22.42 Source: Worldbank (2003), Glewwe et al. (2002) Table 4 shows the ethnic and gender dimensions of poverty in Vietnam. Both are strongly related to the spatial dimension. Vietnam’s ethnic minorities live in the less populated rural regions and account for the increasing share of these regions in the contribution to overall poverty. Across all regions the data reveal that ethnic minorities did not only enjoy a much smaller reduction of absolute poverty. The gender dimension of Vietnam’s poverty profile with female-headed households showing less poverty then male-headed households. However, the gender of the household head is only a very rough indicator of differences in well being between men and women. Other indicators will be analyzed below. Female-headed households are usually smaller, are more typical in urban areas and often receive remittances from husbands working elsewhere in the country or overseas (UNDP 2003). Rural female headed households, however, are usually very poor or face a very high vulnerability of falling into poverty (Man Loi 1996, Centre for International Development 2002). Table 5: Socio-characteristics of Vietnam’s poverty profile HEADCOUNT INDEX (IN %) SHARE OF POPULATION %) 1993 1998 2002 1993 1998 2002 1. National Poverty 58.1 37.4 28.9 100.0 100.0 100.0 2. Household size Small (≤ 3 members) 45.95 16.95 16.69 12.22 12.14 14.83 Medium (3-6 members) 56.86 30.80 25.46 36.36 44.10 50.25 Large (≥ 6 members) 64.72 49.66 41.62 51.43 43.76 34.93 3. Number of children Number of children ≤ 2 55.92 34.33 24.80 48.69 56.60 57.07 Number of children 2-5 61.57 39.92 33.73 34.81 32.62 32.36 Number of children ≥ 5 66.11 45.64 44.75 16.50 10.79 10.58 4. Occupation of the household head (*) White collar 23.6 9.9 29.27 4.6 6.6 6.18 Sales 27.7 13.0 32.84 8.1 9.5 14.80 Agriculture 69.0 48.2 26.85 64.7 61.0 51.73 Production 45.9 26.0 38.55 10.9 11.5 14.20 Other/no work 44.4 27.4 28.83 11.7 11.3 13.10 5. Education of the household head No schooling 62.6 55.0 37.01 36.1 35.5 31.58 Primary 56.7 42.2 32.24 24.4 23.1 24.52 Low secondary 64.0 38.0 29.32 23.4 22.4 26.47 Upper secondary 44.5 25.1 18.46 4.7 5.2 8.39 Technical worker, vocational school or university degree 39.2 14.2 9.97 7.9 13.8 9.04 Source: Worldbank (2003), Glewwe et al. (2002) 2.3 Summary of characteristics of poverty in Vietnam - The poor in Viet Nam are less educated and less skilled; has more children but less access to l and and credit; spends less on education and has less health insurance coverage; lacks opportunities to earn income and is more vulnerable e to external shocks and risks (Vu Quoc Huy, 2002). - Poverty incidence was more prevalent and more persistent among ethnic minorities. Ethnic minority households are larger and have more children than the average. The educational attainment of household heads and spouses is lower. Endowments in terms of housing and other assets are also below average. The compounded effect of all these characteristics is such that minority households are substantially poorer. The share of ethnic minorities among the poor is al so increasing steadily, from 20 per cent in 1993 to more than 30 per cent by 2002. The upward trend is even stronger if food poverty is considered instead. The share of ethnic minorities among the food-poor increased from less than 30 percent in 1993 to almost 53 percent in 2002. - The poor generally have low levels of educational attainment. Although poverty incidence has dropped for every level of educational attainment over the 1990s, the poor have relatively low levels of educational attainment. The highest incidence of poverty (40 percent) is for those w ho have not completed primary school. In 2002, the poor had the lowest literacy rate (less than 90 percent) compared with the non-poor. About one fourth of the poor have not finished primary school. The highest education attainment for another two thirds of them is primary and lower secondary school. Less than 2 percent of them have education higher than upper secondary level (table 5). - The overwhelming majority of the poor (92 percent) live in rural areas. Poverty is al so very much associated with ethnic minorities living in isolated and mountainous areas such as the Northern Uplands and the Central Highlands. CHAPTER IV ESTIMATION RESULTS OF HOUSEHOLD WELFARE This chapter will use econometric models to explore determinants of the household welfare in rural Vietnam. This chapter has three sections, First section introduces data, second is to introduces variables and the third is results of econometric models. The econometrics model in the household welfare index equation. DATA This study is based on Vietnam Living Standards Survey (VLSS) carried out by General Statistic Office (GSO) in 2002. Survey sample consists of 29532 households with about 132000 people in Vietnam. The survey provides detailed information about employment, income, level of education, and demographic characteristics of household members. The survey also contains valuable information of household such as other income and total land area. This analysis is confined to household possessing annual crop land as production in rural area nationwide. The final data sample has 9523 household; in 8 regions described as below (table 5) Table 5: Number of household by region Region Number of household Percentage Cumulative Red River Delt

Các file đính kèm theo tài liệu này:

  • doc11098.doc
Tài liệu liên quan